• Documents
  • Authors
  • Tables
  • Log in
  • Sign up
  • MetaCart
  • DMCA
  • Donate

CiteSeerX logo

Advanced Search Include Citations
Advanced Search Include Citations

Trust and the development of health care as a social institution. (2003)

by L Gilson
Venue:Social Science & Medicine,
Add To MetaCart

Tools

Sorted by:
Results 1 - 10 of 106
Next 10 →

Output-based payment to boost staff productivity in public health centres: contracting

by Bruno Meessen , Jean-Pierre I Kashala , Laurent Musango - in Kabutare district, Rwanda’, Bulletin of the World Health Organization , 2007
"... Objective In many low-income countries, public health systems do not meet the needs and demands of the population. We aimed to assess the extent to which output-based payment could boost staff productivity at health care facilities. Methods We assessed the performance of 15 health care centres in K ..."
Abstract - Cited by 11 (2 self) - Add to MetaCart
Objective In many low-income countries, public health systems do not meet the needs and demands of the population. We aimed to assess the extent to which output-based payment could boost staff productivity at health care facilities. Methods We assessed the performance of 15 health care centres in Kabutare, Rwanda, comparing productivity in 2001, when fixed annual bonuses were paid to staff, with that in 2003, when an output-based payment incentive scheme was implemented. Findings Changes to the structure of contracts were associated with improvements in health centre performance: specifically, output-based performance contracts induced sharp increases in the productivity of health staff. Conclusion Institutional configurations of health care organizations deserve more attention. Those currently in place in the public sector may not the most suitable to meet current challenges in health care. More experiments are needed to confirm these early results from Rwanda and elsewhere, since risks associated with output-based incentive schemes should not be ignored. Introduction Public health systems in low-income countries do not always live up to expectations. Poor performance in terms of coverage of needs, equity, quality of care, responsiveness to users and efficiency has been extensively documented. 1-3 Without major changes, especially in the delivery of primary health care, the health status in most rural populations will not achieve the significant improvements that are needed to meet the Millennium Development Goals. 8 Before poor performance can be addressed, the extent to which the problems can be remedied by staff at the health facilities should be ascertained. Obviously, some aspects related to the Before trying to tackle a problem, it is appropriate to view it in a broad context. One must be fair towards the health staff. Many problems that are observed at the level of the public health facilities are also reported in other governmentrun bodies such as schools and the civil administration. 3 Some pro-market proponents may see these problems as an opportunity to discredit any role for the state in service provision. Opponents to this argument may instead place blame on poverty and limited capacity within the country; they will invite us to have patience and, in the meantime, to accept that some problems have their roots beyond the health sector. In this paper, we discuss a third way for problem resolution, exploring the extent to which the performance of public health facilities could be enhanced by reform of some key institutions that establish them as organizations. We focus on only one dimension of performance, that of staff productivity and present results of the performance initiative, an output-based payment approach currently being trialed in the Kabutare district of Rwanda. Methods Institutional configurations in health care Institutional arrangements, contracts and organizations have been very dynamic fields of research for economists in the past 40 years. Today, economists have a much better understanding of the influence of factors such as asymmetry of information, transaction costs and property rights on institutional shape and performance of organizations. ‫املقالة.‬ ‫لهذه‬ ‫الكامل‬ ‫النص‬ ‫نهاية‬ ‫يف‬ ‫الخالصة‬ ‫لهذه‬ ‫العربية‬ ‫الرتجمة‬ As far as institutional arrangements are concerned, there are probably two key factors that determine the performance of a health care organization. 1 First, there is the whole set of contracts that establishes the way an organization accesses the physical resources necessary to produce health services (hereafter called "physical resource contracts"). There has been much written about methods by which an organization accesses its cash income (e.g. fees-forservice, capitation, budget-line items). 17 Yet, cash is only one of many types of resource. For example, receiving standard drug kits free of charge is not equivalent to paying the full price for drugs that one has ordered. 2 The second key determinant of performance is the set of contracts that establishes the way in which those who hold discretionary authority over the allocation of resources mainly the owner, manager and health staff are remunerated by the organization (hereafter called the "governance and employment contracts"). The combination of both sets of contracts establishes a nexus that makes up the institutional configuration of the health care organization. There are as many possible institutional configurations as there are possible combinations of different contracts. Yet, from the perspective of the organization's stakeholders, some configurations are better than others, which explains why some configurations occur more frequently than others. One must note that creativity is not limited to the design of contracts; the distribution of roles is also a variable. An illustrative case is that of the single private practice, characterized by an individual who occupies the positions of owner, manager and employee. This arrangement has not occurred by chance: economists have shown that such an institutional configuration solves several problems that arise when one party (e.g. an employer) engages another party (e.g. an employee) to act on their behalf and in their interest -the so-called "principal-agent problem". This configuration contrasts with the situation of public health centres, which are owned by the state (with the citizens as the ultimate owners), managed by a civil servant affiliated with the ministry of health and operated by other civil servants with fixed salaries. There is no miracle solution; each configuration has its advantages and disadvantages. Typically, a configuration will be particularly well suited for one dimension of performance (e.g. the efficient use of resources) but less suited for another (e.g. quality of care). The existing literature on provider payment contracts has brought attention to this trade-off. Yet, the existence of tradeoffs should not mean acceptance of the status quo. Our intuition, not only as researchers but also as workers who have been directly involved in the operation of public health systems, is that the configurations in place today in many low-income countries have more disadvantages than advantages. We wonder whether more powerful incentives for the health staff could provide the way forward to improved services in health care. We use the case of an experience in Rwanda to illustrate our proposition. Before the introduction of the performance initiative, staff at the 15 health centres had benefited from a fixed-bonus system (in addition to salaries). This system, inherited from post-war reconstruction strategies, had been taken over by HNI from the previous NGO that was supporting the district. The rule was that health centres received a budget that was calculated according to the number and qualification of employed individuals. Under the new scheme, individuals kept their base salaries (paid by the government or the health facility with revenue raised through user fees), but an output-based remuneration to the health centre replaced the fixed-bonus system. Payments for services were set for some key services delivered by the health facility (see Box 1). The performance initiative in Formalization and the data source With some simplifications, we can use a mathematical formulae to compare the two institutional configurations. We have limited our analysis to the health centre (we did not analyse the whole health system and institutional changes at that level). Furthermore, our focus is on the two contracts that have changed significantly: (1) the support in cash funds provided by the NGO to the health centre; and (2) staff remuneration. We have simplified these contracts to their core logic (i.e. we do not formalize the complementary rules and restrictions in the actual contracts). To avoid the issue of differences between individual staff members with respect to bonuses, we have used average amounts per worker at each centre. Box 1. Fees paid to health centres under the performance initiative The performance initiative remunerates the health centres on a payment-for-service model (with a purchaser that is different from the user). In 2003, the payments for purchased services were as follows: -RWF 40 per consultation (new case); -RWF 250 per pregnant woman who received between 2nd and 5th dose of tetanus toxoid (TT); -RWF 1 000 per new acceptor of family planning; -RWF 500 per fully immunised child; -RWF 2 500 per assisted delivery. No change. Vaccines and vertical programme items They are supplied for free by the national programme. No change. Cash The health centre charges users for (i) drugs (with a mark-up), and (ii) for curative consultations and acts. (i) and (ii) no change. A third-party payer (a "steering committee") pays a feefor-services for a limited list of curative and preventive services (see Box 1); the scheme is established by a contract that sets clear obligations upon the health centre; an independent agency checks the reality of reported figures. Equipment Accessed mainly through donation, free utilization by the health centre. No change. Building Owned by the government, a congregation or the parish; free utilization. No change. Other Bought on the market by the health centre with its cash income. No change. Governance and employment contracts Ownership and constrains on the owners A health centre is a combination of multiple owners. The land and the building are owned by the main owner (the government, a congregation or the parish). Equipment, drugs and financial assets are owned by the "health committee" (a community body). All health centres are run as non-profit organisations. The Rwandan Ministry of Health oversees all of them. There has been no formal change of this set-up. Yet, a new "management committee" has been established. It empowers the staff and put them in a position to take and enforce decisions to boost health centre performance. Management (i) The health centre is headed by a head nurse. (ii) He is expected to implement policies made by the Rwandan Ministry of Health. (i) The same, but higher involvement of staff (see above). (ii) The health district authorities leave more discretion to the health centre team for initiatives. Labour (i) Salaries of some qualified staff are paid by the government. (ii) Salaries of some qualified and all non-qualified staff are paid by the health centre with its cash income. (iii) Fixed bonuses are paid to most of the staff by the NGO. (i) and (ii) no change. (iii) The NGO a does not pay a fixed bonus. The (variable) monthly revenue collected from the performance initiative scheme is shared among the staff. An individual share is fixed by a grid that takes into account qualification, responsibility and presence at work. Bonus cuts can be used as a disciplinary measure. NGO, non-governmental organization. In general terms, one could then say that yearly income for the health centre team j is: where nj is the number of staff members, w is the average individual wage paid by the government or the health facility, b is the average individual fixed bonus paid by the NGO, p is the vector [1 × k] of prices for the vector [k × 1] of services Q, and a is the share of the output-based income distributed among the staff. As there have been no major changes in the policy of the government with respect to wages, we can assume that this element of the equation is constant and not relevant in our comparison. Then we can define Y ′ as the income paid to the health centre team by the NGO. The situation before the performance initiative can then be expressed as: Y ′ F,j = nj . b (with F as "fixed bonus") and the one after the performance initiative as Y ′PI,j = a.p.Q (with PI as "performance initiative"). This formalization allows us to identify the two behavioural assumptions behind the performance initiative: (1) that health staff would value higher average individual incomes, and (2) Q is partly determined by the behaviour of health staff. Our analyses are based on the data used by the NGO to monitor the performance initiative. We will make the simplifying assumption that all the changes observed in the production of the health centres stem from change to the contracts. Although a strong causality has already been shown, we acknowledge that this assumption is somewhat excessive. 19 For the exchange rates, we have used the average over the period 2001-03 (US$ 1 = RWF 483). Results During preparations for the new scheme in early 2002, different scenarios were considered and financial simulations were performed accordingly. The main goal was to determine the prices that would be used for buying the health centres' outputs (eventual prices are shown in Box 1). The rules were as follows: This arrangement is illustrated in The Y ′PI (2003) column in The goal of measuring output gains is to assess whether the NGO received value for money. Ouput gain (Y ′PI (2003) -Y ′PI (2001)) gives a monetary value to the increase in outputs (along the fee-based index). Our data show that incentives do make a difference: all health centre teams have increased their outputs, even those that experienced a drop in income. The relative increases in output shown in A comparison of simulated average individual bonuses due with 2001 production

Maternity referral systems in developing countries: Current knowledge and future research needs. Social Science and Medicine, Ahead of print

by Susan F Murray , Stephen C Pearson , 2005
"... Abstract A functioning referral system is generally considered to be a necessary element of successful Safe Motherhood programmes. This paper draws on a scoping review of available literature to identify key requisites for successful maternity referral systems in developing countries, to highlight ..."
Abstract - Cited by 8 (0 self) - Add to MetaCart
Abstract A functioning referral system is generally considered to be a necessary element of successful Safe Motherhood programmes. This paper draws on a scoping review of available literature to identify key requisites for successful maternity referral systems in developing countries, to highlight knowledge gaps, and to suggest items for a future research agenda. Key online social science, medical and health system bibliographic databases, and websites were searched in July 2004 for evidence relating to referral systems for maternity care. Documentary evidence on implementation is scarce, but it suggests that many healthcare systems in developing countries are failing to optimise women's rapid access to emergency obstetric care, and that the poor and marginalised are affected disproportionately. Likely requisites for successful maternity referral systems include: a referral strategy informed by the assessment of population needs and health system capabilities; an adequately resourced referral centre; active collaboration between referral levels and across sectors; formalised communication and transport arrangements; agreed setting-specific protocols for referrer and receiver; supervision and accountability for providers' performance; affordable service costs; the capacity to monitor effectiveness; and underpinning all of these, policy support. Theoretically informed social and organisational research is required on the referral care needs of the poor and marginalised, on the maternity workforce and organisation, and on the implications of the mixed economy of healthcare for referral networks. Clinical research is required to determine how maternity referral fits within newborn health priorities and where the needs are different. Finally, research is required to determine how and whether a more integrated approach to emergency care systems may benefit women and their communities.
(Show Context)

Citation Context

... the effectiveness of lady health workers (LHWs) in Punjab, Pakistan. Uniformly, male management structures disadvantaged these female community workers. Managers were routinely unsupportive, even abusive, and when such LHWs referred women to the hospital, their patients were ARTICLE IN PRESS S.F. Murray, S.C. Pearson / Social Science & Medicine 62 (2006) 2205–2215 2211ignored. Such studies raise important questions about what it is reasonable to expect without additional supportive interventions around gender issues. They also highlight the ‘‘inherently relational’’ nature of health systems (Gilson, 2003, p. 1453). Pro-poor protection against the costs of emergency referral The social structures, power dynamics, and underlying injustices that maintain inequities in access to healthcare form the backdrop to this paper (Hawkins, Newman, Thomas, & Carlson, 2005). Significant negative associations between women’s poverty status (as proxied by educational level, source of water, and type of toilet and floor) and maternal survival have been shown through analysis of Demographic and Health Survey data from 10 diverse developing countries (Graham, Fitzmaurice, Bell, & Cairns, 2004). With increasing p...

Health systems, communicable diseases and integration. Health Policy Plan. 2010;25(Suppl 1):i420

by Altynay Shigayeva, Rifat Atun, Martin Mckee, Richard Coker
"... The HIV/AIDS, tuberculosis and malaria pandemics pose substantial challenges globally and to health systems in the countries they affect. This demands an institutional approach that can integrate disease control programmes within health and social care systems. Whilst integration is intuitively appe ..."
Abstract - Cited by 6 (0 self) - Add to MetaCart
The HIV/AIDS, tuberculosis and malaria pandemics pose substantial challenges globally and to health systems in the countries they affect. This demands an institutional approach that can integrate disease control programmes within health and social care systems. Whilst integration is intuitively appealing, evidence of its benefits remains uncertain and evaluation is beset by lack of a common understanding of what it involves. The aim of this paper is to better define integration in health systems relevant to communicable disease control. We conducted a critical review of published literature on concepts, definitions, and analytical and methodological approaches to integration as applied to health system responses to communicable disease. We found that integration is under-stood and pursued in many ways in different health systems. We identified a variety of typologies that relate to three fundamental questions associated with integration: (1) why is integration a goal (that is, what are the driving forces for integration); (2) what structures and/or functions at different levels of health system are affected by integration (or the lack of); and (3) how does integration

Ridde V: Contextual factors as a key to understanding the heterogeneity of effects of a maternal health policy in Burkina Faso. Health Pol Plann

by Loubna Belaid , Valéry Ridde , 2014
"... Burkina Faso implemented a national subsidy for emergency obstetric and neonatal care (EmONC) covering 80% of the cost of normal childbirth in public health facilities. The objective was to increase coverage of facility-based deliveries. After implementation of the EmONC policy, coverage increased ..."
Abstract - Cited by 6 (0 self) - Add to MetaCart
Burkina Faso implemented a national subsidy for emergency obstetric and neonatal care (EmONC) covering 80% of the cost of normal childbirth in public health facilities. The objective was to increase coverage of facility-based deliveries. After implementation of the EmONC policy, coverage increased across the country, but disparities were observed between districts and between primary healthcare centres (PHC). To understand the variation in coverage, we assessed the contextual factors and the implementation of EmONC in six PHCs in a district. We conducted a contrasted multiple case study. We interviewed women (n ¼ 71), traditional birth attendants (n ¼ 7), clinic management committees (n ¼ 11), and health workers and district health managers (n ¼ 26). Focus groups (n ¼ 62) were conducted within communities. Observations were carried out in the six PHCs. Implementation was nearly homogeneous in the six PHCs but the contexts and human factors appeared to explain the variations observed on the coverage of facility-based deliveries. In the PHCs of Nogo and Tara, the immediate increase in coverage was attributed to health workers' leadership in creatively promoting facility-based deliveries and strengthening relationships of trust with communities, users' positive perceptions of quality of care and the arrival of female professional staff. The change of healthcare team at Iata's PHC and a penalty fee imposed for home births in Belem may have caused the delayed effects there. Finally, the unchanged coverage in the PHCs of Fati and Mata was likely due to lack of promotion of facility-based deliveries, users' negative perceptions of quality of care, and conflicts between health workers and users. Before implementation, decision-makers should perform pilot studies to adapt policies according to contexts and human factors.
(Show Context)

Citation Context

...sidered important actors within communities. A study in Ethiopia has shown that women prefer home birth assisted by a TBA, who is still a culturally important figure (Shiferaw et al. 2013). Another study has shown how integrating midwives at the community level has a positive influence on the health system, specifically in countries with limited resources (Sherratt 2013). However, the literature on leadership in LMIC is sparse, and policy changes in LMIC are still ‘considered to be situated at the top level of the health system and more focused on financial and administrative considerations’ (Gilson 2003; Haddad et al. 2009). Our research findings suggest strongly that it is time to focus on making changes at the bottom of the health system pyramid to foster health workers’ empowerment and leadership, because they make a difference in health outcomes and are key actors in the success of health policies. In fact, several studies have shown how the leadership of health district managers has contributed to better performance in health indicators (Gilson et al. 2005; Haddad et al. 2009; Meda et al. 2011). Assessing context: essential for interpretation of health policies A major weakness in analy...

Improving Health Outcomes By Choosing Better Doctors: Evidence of Social Learning about Doctor Quality from Rural Tanzania.” working paper

by Kenneth L. Leonard, Robert Saidi, The Barrett Kirwan, Andreas Lange, Loretta Lynch, Erik Lichtenberg, Marc Nerlove , 2007
"... Households in Africa and indeed almost everywhere, face a choice of health care providers with only limited information about the relative quality of these providers. Unlike households in developed counties, however, rural African households make choices among providers of highly variable quality fo ..."
Abstract - Cited by 4 (0 self) - Add to MetaCart
Households in Africa and indeed almost everywhere, face a choice of health care providers with only limited information about the relative quality of these providers. Unlike households in developed counties, however, rural African households make choices among providers of highly variable quality for illnesses that are frequently severe and they must do so without access to formal sources of information or any insurance against the consequences of bad outcomes. In spite of—or because of—these difficulties, households in rural Tanzania do learn about and react to the quality of health care providers. In this paper, I examine a two year panel of health seeking behavior for over 500 households in rural Northern Tanzania where households face choices between forty modern health care providers. This paper shows (1) that house-holds change the way they visit new providers as they learn about quality, visiting better providers for marginally more severe illnesses and (2) households improve their outcomes as they learn about quality by choosing the appropriate doctors when they are sick. This findings have important implications for our understanding of the market for health care quality and the demand for health care more generally.

Formative Evaluation of the

by In The, Mr Paul Tyler , 2006
"... rationale for this is that the evaluation team felt that a more detailed, as opposed to a précis, account of the results of the 44 interviews conducted was important given that: • the Social Capital Project was a new and innovative pilot initiative and as such had not been previously documented in a ..."
Abstract - Cited by 3 (0 self) - Add to MetaCart
rationale for this is that the evaluation team felt that a more detailed, as opposed to a précis, account of the results of the 44 interviews conducted was important given that: • the Social Capital Project was a new and innovative pilot initiative and as such had not been previously documented in a comprehensive manner; • the Social Capital Project has involved a range of diverse stakeholders, many of whom had not had access to information about aspects of the Project that they had not immediately been involved in. This report was seen as one of the ways in which the different experiences of the Project could be shared; and • considering the evaluation was formative in nature, it was considered important to demonstrate the evidence base from which recommendations for the future of the Project were made. Having outlined the above, the team is aware that many readers will only be able to read some aspects of the report. For this reason the first 8 chapters of the report have been written in a discrete way: each containing a conclusion at the end of the

Active Patients’ in Rural African Health Care: Implications for Welfare, Policy and Privatization,” mimeo (available on-line

by Kenneth L. Leonard , 2001
"... We introduce the ‘active patient ’ model, which we claim is a better way to describe health-seeking behaviour in low-income countries. Active patients do not automatically seek health care at the closest or lowest cost provider, but rather seek high-quality care (even at higher cost) when they estim ..."
Abstract - Cited by 2 (1 self) - Add to MetaCart
We introduce the ‘active patient ’ model, which we claim is a better way to describe health-seeking behaviour in low-income countries. Active patients do not automatically seek health care at the closest or lowest cost provider, but rather seek high-quality care (even at higher cost) when they estimate that such care will significantly improves outcomes. We show how the active patient can improve his or her health even when access to adequate quality care is insufficient and that the empirical literature supports this model, particularly in Africa. Finally, we demonstrate the importance, in analysing health care policy, of recognizing patients ’ efforts to improve health outcomes by seeking quality care.

Between Profit and Legitimacy A Case Study of Two Successful Township Health

by Lijie Fang, Gerald Bloom
"... The Township Health Centers (THCs), which serve China’s rural residents are hospitals with Chinese characteristics. A comparative study of two THCs found that their performance is linked to their successful adaptation to the new economic and institutional context within which they operate. It found ..."
Abstract - Cited by 2 (2 self) - Add to MetaCart
The Township Health Centers (THCs), which serve China’s rural residents are hospitals with Chinese characteristics. A comparative study of two THCs found that their performance is linked to their successful adaptation to the new economic and institutional context within which they operate. It found that health facility managers need to balance the need to generate revenue with the need to maintain their good reputation with government and the community It identified three major influences on their performance: the pattern of economic incentives, formal and informal rules of behavior and the history and management arrangements of the facility. It concluded that tailoring administrative rules to embrace the market, responding actively to social expectations and proper selection of THC director are all beneficial to THC performance.
(Show Context)

Citation Context

...nance of the facility’s reputation (Mackintosh and Tibandebages2002). The effective performance of the health sector requires a relativelyshigh level of trust between providers and users of services (=-=Gilson 2003-=-).sOne way to understand the institutional arrangements in the health sector issin terms of a social contract between actors, underpinned by sharedsbehavioral norms, and embedded in a broader politica...

Looking Beneath the Urban Averages: The Effects of Household and Neighborhood Poverty on Health

by Mark R. Montgomery, Paul C. Hewett , 2003
"... York 10017; ..."
Abstract - Cited by 1 (0 self) - Add to MetaCart
York 10017;

Exploring health researchers' perceptions of policymaking in Argentina: A qualitative study. Health Policy and Planning

by Adrijana Corluka, Adnan A Hyder, Peter J Winch, Elsa Segura
"... Much of the published research on evidence-informed health policymaking in low- and middle-income countries has focused on policymakers, overlooking the role of health researchers in the research-to-policy process. Through 20 semi-structured, in-depth qualitative interviews conducted with researcher ..."
Abstract - Cited by 1 (1 self) - Add to MetaCart
Much of the published research on evidence-informed health policymaking in low- and middle-income countries has focused on policymakers, overlooking the role of health researchers in the research-to-policy process. Through 20 semi-structured, in-depth qualitative interviews conducted with researchers in Argentina’s rural northwest and the capital of Buenos Aires, we explore the perspectives, experiences and attitudes of Argentine health researchers regarding the use and impact of health research in policymaking in Argentina. We find that the researcher, and the researcher’s function of generating evidence, is nested within a broader complex system that influences the researcher’s interaction with policymaking. This system comprises communities of practice, government departments/civil society organizations, bureaucratic processes and political governance and executive leadership. At the individual level, researcher capacity and determinants of research availability also play a role in contributing to evidence-informed policymaking. In addition, we find a recurrent theme around ‘lack of trust ’ and explore the role of trust within a research system,
Powered by: Apache Solr
  • About CiteSeerX
  • Submit and Index Documents
  • Privacy Policy
  • Help
  • Data
  • Source
  • Contact Us

Developed at and hosted by The College of Information Sciences and Technology

© 2007-2019 The Pennsylvania State University