Results 1 - 10
of
73
Selection, growth, and the size distribution of firms
- Quarterly Journal of Economics
, 2007
"... This paper describes an analytically tractable model of balanced growth that is consistent with the observed size distribution of firms. Growth is the result of idiosyncratic firm productivity improvements, selection of successful firms, and imitation by entrants. Selection tends to improve aggregat ..."
Abstract
-
Cited by 54 (0 self)
- Add to MetaCart
This paper describes an analytically tractable model of balanced growth that is consistent with the observed size distribution of firms. Growth is the result of idiosyncratic firm productivity improvements, selection of successful firms, and imitation by entrants. Selection tends to improve aggregate productivity at a fast rate if entry and imitation are easy. The empirical phenomenon of Zipf ’s law can be interpreted to mean that entry costs are high or that imitation is difficult, or both. The small size of entrants indicates that imitation must be difficult. A calibration based on U. S. data suggests that about half of output growth can be attributed to selection. But the implied variance of the combined preference and technology shocks is puzzlingly high. I.
Entrepreneurial Finance and Non-diversifiable Risk
, 2008
"... Entrepreneurs face significant non-diversifiable business risks. In a dynamic incomplete-markets model of entrepreneurial finance, we show that such risks have important implications for their interdependent consumption/saving, portfolio choice, financing, investment, and endogenous default/cash-out ..."
Abstract
-
Cited by 22 (7 self)
- Add to MetaCart
Entrepreneurs face significant non-diversifiable business risks. In a dynamic incomplete-markets model of entrepreneurial finance, we show that such risks have important implications for their interdependent consumption/saving, portfolio choice, financing, investment, and endogenous default/cash-out decisions. Even though more risk-averse entrepreneurs default earlier for given debt service, they choose higher leverage ex ante for diversification benefits. Entrepreneurs demand not only a systematic risk premium but also an idiosyncratic risk premium due to the lack of diversification. We derive an analytical formula for the idiosyncratic risk premium whose key determinants are risk aversion, idiosyncratic volatility and the sensitivity of entrepreneurial value of equity with respect to cash flow. An entrepreneur’s option to use external equity improves diversification and raises the private value of firm, but it partially crowds out the value of diversification via external risky debt and hence lowers leverage. Finally, after debt is in place, when an entrepreneur chooses among mutually exclusive projects with different idiosyncratic volatilities, the effect of risk aversion tends to dominate the risk-shifting incentives. Only entrepreneurs with very low risk aversion engage in risk-shifting activities.
Growth to value: Option exercise and the cross section of equity returns, Working Paper
, 2012
"... We put forward an equilibrium model that provides a link between the cross section of expected returns and book-to-market characteristics. We model two primitive assets: value assets, and growth assets that are options on assets in place. The cost of option exercise, which is endogenously determined ..."
Abstract
-
Cited by 21 (1 self)
- Add to MetaCart
We put forward an equilibrium model that provides a link between the cross section of expected returns and book-to-market characteristics. We model two primitive assets: value assets, and growth assets that are options on assets in place. The cost of option exercise, which is endogenously determined in equilibrium, is highly procyclical and acts as a hedge against risks in assets in place. Consequently, growth options are less risky than value assets, and the model features a value premium. Our model incorporates long-run risks in aggregate consumption (as in Bansal and Yaron (2004)) and replicates the empirical failure of the conditional CAPM prediction. We calibrate the model and show that it is able to quantitatively account for the observed pattern in mean returns on book-to-market sorted portfolios, the magnitude of the CAPM-alphas, and other silent features of the cross-sectional data.
Firm Heterogeneity and the Long-Run Effects of Dividend Tax Reform
, 2006
"... What are the long-run effects of dividend taxation on aggregate capital accumulation and welfare? To address this question, we build a dynamic general equilibrium model in which there is a continuum of firms subject to idiosyncratic productivity shocks. We show that at any point in time, a firm may ..."
Abstract
-
Cited by 18 (4 self)
- Add to MetaCart
What are the long-run effects of dividend taxation on aggregate capital accumulation and welfare? To address this question, we build a dynamic general equilibrium model in which there is a continuum of firms subject to idiosyncratic productivity shocks. We show that at any point in time, a firm may lie in one of three finance regimes: dividend distribution regime, liquidity constrained regime, and equity issuance regime. These finance regimes may change over time in response to idiosyncratic productivity shocks. Firms in different finance regimes respond to dividend taxation in different ways. We calibrate our model to the US data from COMPUSTAT and use this calibrated model to provide an initial quantitative evaluation of the Bush government dividend tax reform in 2003. Our baseline model simulations show that when both dividend and capital gains tax rates are cut from 25 and 20 percent, respectively, to the same 15 percent level permanently, the aggregate long-run capital stock increases by about 3 percent and welfare measured by consumption increases by about 0.6 percent. This result is robust to small changes of parameter values and to several extensions of our baseline model.
Firm Dynamics and Financial Development ∗
, 2009
"... This paper studies the impact of cross-country variation in financial market development on firms’ financing choices and growth rates using comprehensive firm-level datasets. We document that in less financially developed economies, small firms grow faster and have lower debt to asset ratios than la ..."
Abstract
-
Cited by 17 (0 self)
- Add to MetaCart
This paper studies the impact of cross-country variation in financial market development on firms’ financing choices and growth rates using comprehensive firm-level datasets. We document that in less financially developed economies, small firms grow faster and have lower debt to asset ratios than large firms. We then develop a quantitative model where financial frictions drive firm growth and debt financing through the availability of credit and default risk. We parameterize the model to the firms ’ financial structure in the data and show that financial restrictions can account for the majority of the difference in growth rates between firms of different sizes across countries.
Agglomeration under forward-looking expectations: Potentials and global stability, Mimeo
, 2006
"... This paper considers a class of migration dynamics with forward-looking agents in a multi-country solvable variant of the core-periphery model of Krugman [Krugman, P., 1991. Increasing returns and economic geography. Journal of Political Economy 99, 483–499]. We find that, under a symmetric external ..."
Abstract
-
Cited by 13 (6 self)
- Add to MetaCart
(Show Context)
This paper considers a class of migration dynamics with forward-looking agents in a multi-country solvable variant of the core-periphery model of Krugman [Krugman, P., 1991. Increasing returns and economic geography. Journal of Political Economy 99, 483–499]. We find that, under a symmetric externality assumption, our static model admits a potential function, which allows us to identify a stationary state that is uniquely absorbing and globally accessible under the perfect foresight dynamics whenever the degree of friction in relocation decisions is sufficiently small. In particular, when trade barriers are low enough, full agglomeration in the country with the highest barrier is the unique stable state for small frictions. New aspects in trade and tax policy that arise due to forward-looking behavior are discussed.
The Dynamics of Mergers and Acquisitions in Oligopolistic Industries
- Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, April 2012
"... This paper develops a continuous time real options model to study the interaction between industry structure and takeover activity. In an asymmetric industry equilibrium, firms have an endogenous incentive to merge when restructuring decisions are motivated by operating and strategic benefits. The m ..."
Abstract
-
Cited by 10 (3 self)
- Add to MetaCart
This paper develops a continuous time real options model to study the interaction between industry structure and takeover activity. In an asymmetric industry equilibrium, firms have an endogenous incentive to merge when restructuring decisions are motivated by operating and strategic benefits. The model predicts that (i) the likelihood of restructuring activities are greater in more concentrated industries or in industries more exposed to exogenous shocks; and (ii) the magnitude of returns arising from restructuring to both merger firms and rival firms are higher in more concentrated industries. While recent real options models contend that competition erodes the option value of waiting and hence accelerates the timing of mergers, increased competition in our model delays the timing of mergers.
Corporate Tax Policy and Long-Run Capital Formation: The Role of Irreversibility and Fixed Costs,” working paper
, 2008
"... This paper presents an analytically tractable continuous-time general equilibrium model with investment irreversibility and fixed adjustment costs. In the model, there is a continuum of firms that are subject to idiosyncratic shocks to capital. Although the presence of investment frictions lowers co ..."
Abstract
-
Cited by 7 (3 self)
- Add to MetaCart
This paper presents an analytically tractable continuous-time general equilibrium model with investment irreversibility and fixed adjustment costs. In the model, there is a continuum of firms that are subject to idiosyncratic shocks to capital. Although the presence of investment frictions lowers consumer welfare, it may raise or reduce the long-run average capital stock, depending on the degree of idiosyncratic uncertainty. An increase in this uncertainty may raise equilibrium aggregate capital, but reduce welfare. An unexpected permanent change in the corporate income tax rate affects the investment trigger and target values, and hence the size and rate of capital adjustment. Following this tax policy, the percentage changes in equilibrium quantities are larger when fixed adjustment costs are larger. These changes are significantly smaller in a general equilibrium model than in a partial equilibrium model.
Financial Development and Economic Volatility: A Unified Explanation
, 2009
"... Empirical studies showed that firm-level volatility has been increasing but the aggregate volatility has been decreasing in the US for the post-war period. This paper proposes a unified explanation for these diverging trends. Our explanation is based on a story of financial development –measured by ..."
Abstract
-
Cited by 7 (7 self)
- Add to MetaCart
Empirical studies showed that firm-level volatility has been increasing but the aggregate volatility has been decreasing in the US for the post-war period. This paper proposes a unified explanation for these diverging trends. Our explanation is based on a story of financial development –measured by the reduction of borrowing constraints because of greater access to external financing and options for risk sharing. By constructing a dynamic stochastic general-equilibrium model of heterogenous firms facing borrowing constraints and investment irreversibility, it is shown that financial liberalization increases the lumpiness of firm-level investment but decreases the variance of aggregate output. Hence, the model predicts that financial development leads to a larger firm-level volatility but a lower aggregate volatility. In addition, our model is also consistent with the observed decline in volatility of private held firms which do not have (or have only limited) access to external funds.